In mathematical optimization, the method of Lagrange multipliers (named after Joseph Louis Lagrange) provides a strategy for finding the maxima and minima of a function subject to constraints.
For instance (see Figure 1), consider the optimization problem
We introduce a new variable () called a Lagrange multiplier, and study the Lagrange function defined by
where the term may be either added or subtracted. If is a maximum for the original constrained problem, then there exists such that is a stationary point for the Lagrange function (stationary points are those points where the partial derivatives of Λ are zero). However, not all stationary points yield a solution of the original problem. Thus, the method of Lagrange multipliers yields a necessary condition for optimality in constrained problems.[1][2][3][4][5]
Contents |
One of the most common problems in calculus is that of finding maxima or minima (in general, "extrema") of a function, but it is often difficult to find a closed form for the function being extremized. Such difficulties often arise when one wishes to maximize or minimize a function subject to fixed outside conditions or constraints. The method of Lagrange multipliers is a powerful tool for solving this class of problems without the need to explicitly solve the conditions and use them to eliminate extra variables.
Consider the two-dimensional problem introduced above:
We can visualize contours of f given by
for various values of , and the contour of given by .
Suppose we walk along the contour line with . In general the contour lines of and may be distinct, so following the contour line for one could intersect with or cross the contour lines of . This is equivalent to saying that while moving along the contour line for the value of can vary. Only when the contour line for meets contour lines of tangentially, do we not increase or decrease the value of — that is, when the contour lines touch but do not cross.
The contour lines of f and g touch when the tangent vectors of the contour lines are parallel. Since the gradient of a function is perpendicular to the contour lines, this is the same as saying that the gradients of f and g are parallel. Thus we want points where and
where
and
are the respective gradients. The constant is required because although the two gradient vectors are parallel, the magnitudes of the gradient vectors are generally not equal.
To incorporate these conditions into one equation, we introduce an auxiliary function
and solve
This is the method of Lagrange multipliers. Note that implies .
The constrained extrema of are critical points of the Lagrangian , but they are not local extrema of (see Example 2 below).
One may reformulate the Lagrangian as a Hamiltonian, in which case the solutions are local minima for the Hamiltonian. This is done in optimal control theory, in the form of Pontryagin's minimum principle.
The fact that solutions of the Lagrangian are not necessarily extrema also poses difficulties for numerical optimization. This can be addressed by computing the magnitude of the gradient, as the zeros of the magnitude are necessarily local minima, as illustrated in the numerical optimization example.
The method of Lagrange multipliers can also accommodate multiple constraints. To see how this is done, we need to reexamine the problem in a slightly different manner because the concept of “crossing” discussed above becomes rapidly unclear when we consider the types of constraints that are created when we have more than one constraint acting together.
As an example, consider a paraboloid with a constraint that is a single point (as might be created if we had 2 line constraints that intersect). The level set (i.e., contour line) clearly appears to “cross” that point and its gradient is clearly not parallel to the gradients of either of the two line constraints. Yet, it is obviously a maximum and a minimum because there is only one point on the paraboloid that meets the constraint.
While this example seems a bit odd, it is easy to understand and is representative of the sort of “effective” constraint that appears quite often when we deal with multiple constraints intersecting. Thus, we take a slightly different approach below to explain and derive the Lagrange Multipliers method with any number of constraints.
Throughout this section, the independent variables will be denoted by and, as a group, we will denote them as . Also, the function being analyzed will be denoted by and the constraints will be represented by the equations .
The basic idea remains essentially the same: if we consider only the points that satisfy the constraints (i.e. are in the constraints), then a point is a stationary point (i.e. a point in a “flat” region) of f if and only if the constraints at that point do not allow movement in a direction where f changes value.
Once we have located the stationary points, we need to do further tests to see if we have found a minimum, a maximum or just a stationary point that is neither.
We start by considering the level set of f at . The set of vectors containing the directions in which we can move and still remain in the same level set are the directions where the value of f does not change (i.e. the change equals zero). Thus, for every vector v in , the following relation must hold:
where the notation above means the -component of the vector v. The equation above can be rewritten in a more compact geometric form that helps our intuition:
This makes it clear that if we are at p, then all directions from this point that do not change the value of f must be perpendicular to (the gradient of f at p).
Now let us consider the effect of the constraints. Each constraint limits the directions that we can move from a particular point and still satisfy the constraint. We can use the same procedure, to look for the set of vectors containing the directions in which we can move and still satisfy the constraint. As above, for every vector v in , the following relation must hold:
From this, we see that at point p, all directions from this point that will still satisfy this constraint must be perpendicular to .
Now we are ready to refine our idea further and complete the method: a point on f is a constrained stationary point if and only if the direction that changes f violates at least one of the constraints. (We can see that this is true because if a direction that changes f did not violate any constraints, then there would a “legal” point nearby with a higher or lower value for f and the current point would then not be a stationary point.)
For a single constraint, we use the statement above to say that at stationary points the direction that changes f is in the same direction that violates the constraint. To determine if two vectors are in the same direction, we note that if two vectors start from the same point and are “in the same direction”, then one vector can always “reach” the other by changing its length and/or flipping to point the opposite way along the same direction line. In this way, we can succinctly state that two vectors point in the same direction if and only if one of them can be multiplied by some real number such that they become equal to the other. So, for our purposes, we require that:
If we now add another simultaneous equation to guarantee that we only perform this test when we are at a point that satisfies the constraint, we end up with 2 simultaneous equations that when solved, identify all constrained stationary points:
Note that the above is a succinct way of writing the equations. Fully expanded, there are simultaneous equations that need to be solved for the variables which are and :
For more than one constraint, the same reasoning applies. If there is more than one constraint active together, each constraint contributes a direction that will violate it. Together, these “violation directions” form a “violation space”, where infinitesimal movement in any direction within the space will violate one or more constraints. Thus, to satisfy multiple constraints we can state (using this new terminology) that at the stationary points, the direction that changes f is in the “violation space” created by the constraints acting jointly.
The violation space created by the constraints consists of all points that can be reached by adding any combination of scaled and/or flipped versions of the individual violation direction vectors. In other words, all the points that are “reachable” when we use the individual violation directions as the basis of the space. Thus, we can succinctly state that v is in the space defined by if and only if there exists a set of “multipliers” such that:
which for our purposes, translates to stating that the direction that changes f at p is in the “violation space” defined by the constraints if and only if:
As before, we now add simultaneous equation to guarantee that we only perform this test when we are at a point that satisfies every constraint, we end up with simultaneous equations that when solved, identify all constrained stationary points:
The method is complete now (from the standpoint of solving the problem of finding stationary points) but as mathematicians delight in doing, these equations can be further condensed into an even more elegant and succinct form. Lagrange must have cleverly noticed that the equations above look like partial derivatives of some larger scalar function L that takes all the and all the as inputs. Next, he might then have noticed that setting every equation equal to zero is exactly what one would have to do to solve for the unconstrained stationary points of that larger function. Finally, he showed that a larger function L with partial derivatives that are exactly the ones we require can be constructed very simply as below:
Solving the equation above for its unconstrained stationary points generates exactly the same stationary points as solving for the constrained stationary points of f under the constraints .
In Lagrange’s honor, the function above is called a Lagrangian, the scalars are called Lagrange Multipliers and this optimization method itself is called The Method of Lagrange Multipliers.
The method of Lagrange multipliers is generalized by the Karush–Kuhn–Tucker conditions, which can also take into account inequality constraints of the form h(x) ≤ c.
Often the Lagrange multipliers have an interpretation as some quantity of interest. To see why this might be the case, observe that:
So, λk is the rate of change of the quantity being optimized as a function of the constraint variable. As examples, in Lagrangian mechanics the equations of motion are derived by finding stationary points of the action, the time integral of the difference between kinetic and potential energy. Thus, the force on a particle due to a scalar potential, , can be interpreted as a Lagrange multiplier determining the change in action (transfer of potential to kinetic energy) following a variation in the particle's constrained trajectory. In economics, the optimal profit to a player is calculated subject to a constrained space of actions, where a Lagrange multiplier is the increase in the value of the objective function due to the relaxation of a given constraint (e.g. through an increase in income or bribery or other means) – the marginal cost of a constraint, called the shadow price.
In control theory this is formulated instead as costate equations.
Suppose one wishes to maximize subject to the constraint . The feasible set is the unit circle, and the level sets of f are diagonal lines (with slope -1), so one can see graphically that the maximum occurs at , and the minimum occurs at .
Formally, set , and
Set the derivative , which yields the system of equations:
As always, the equation ((iii) here) is the original constraint.
Combining the first two equations yields (explicitly, , otherwise (i) yields 1 = 0, so one has ).
Substituting into (iii) yields , so and , showing the stationary points are and . Evaluating the objective function f on these yields
thus the maximum is , which is attained at , and the minimum is , which is attained at .
Suppose one wants to find the maximum values of
with the condition that the x and y coordinates lie on the circle around the origin with radius √3, that is, subject to the constraint
As there is just a single constraint, we will use only one multiplier, say λ.
The constraint g(x, y)-3 is identically zero on the circle of radius √3. So any multiple of g(x, y)-3 may be added to f(x, y) leaving f(x, y) unchanged in the region of interest (above the circle where our original constraint is satisfied). Let
The critical values of occur where its gradient is zero. The partial derivatives are
Equation (iii) is just the original constraint. Equation (i) implies or λ = −y. In the first case, if x = 0 then we must have by (iii) and then by (ii) λ = 0. In the second case, if λ = −y and substituting into equation (ii) we have that,
Then x2 = 2y2. Substituting into equation (iii) and solving for y gives this value of y:
Thus there are six critical points:
Evaluating the objective at these points, we find
Therefore, the objective function attains the global maximum (subject to the constraints) at and the global minimum at The point is a local minimum and is a local maximum, as may be determined by consideration of the Hessian matrix of .
Note that while is a critical point of , it is not a local extremum. We have . Given any neighborhood of , we can choose a small positive and a small of either sign to get values both greater and less than .
Suppose we wish to find the discrete probability distribution on the points with maximal information entropy. This is the same as saying that we wish to find the least biased probability distribution on the points . In other words, we wish to maximize the Shannon entropy equation:
For this to be a probability distribution the sum of the probabilities at each point must equal 1, so our constraint is = 1:
We use Lagrange multipliers to find the point of maximum entropy, , across all discrete probability distributions on . We require that:
which gives a system of n equations, , such that:
Carrying out the differentiation of these n equations, we get
This shows that all are equal (because they depend on λ only). By using the constraint ∑j pj = 1, we find
Hence, the uniform distribution is the distribution with the greatest entropy, among distributions on n points.
With Lagrange multipliers, the critical points occur at saddle points, rather than at local maxima (or minima). Unfortunately, many numerical optimization techniques, such as hill climbing, gradient descent, some of the quasi-Newton methods, among others, are designed to find local maxima (or minima) and not saddle points. For this reason, one must either modify the formulation to ensure that it's a minimization problem (for example, by extremizing the square of the gradient of the Lagrangian as below), or else use an optimization technique that finds stationary points (such as Newton's method without an extremum seeking line search) and not necessarily extrema.
As a simple example, consider the problem of finding the value of x that minimizes , constrained such that . (This problem is somewhat pathological because there are only two values that satisfy this constraint, but it is useful for illustration purposes because the corresponding unconstrained function can be visualized in three dimensions.)
Using Lagrange multipliers, this problem can be converted into an unconstrained optimization problem:
The two critical points occur at saddle points where and .
In order to solve this problem with a numerical optimization technique, we must first transform this problem such that the critical points occur at local minima. This is done by computing the magnitude of the gradient of the unconstrained optimization problem.
First, we compute the partial derivative of the unconstrained problem with respect to each variable:
If the target function is not easily differentiable, the differential with respect to each variable can be approximated as
where is a small value.
Next, we compute the magnitude of the gradient, which is the square root of the sum of the squares of the partial derivatives:
(Since magnitude is always non-negative, optimizing over the squared-magnitude is equivalent to optimizing over the magnitude. Thus, the ``square root" may be omitted from these equations with no expected difference in the results of optimization.)
The critical points of h occur at and , just as in . Unlike the critical points in , however, the critical points in h occur at local minima, so numerical optimization techniques can be used to find them.
Constrained optimization plays a central role in economics. For example, the choice problem for a consumer is represented as one of maximizing a utility function subject to a budget constraint. The Lagrange multiplier has an economic interpretation as the shadow price associated with the constraint, in this example the marginal utility of income.
In optimal control theory, the Lagrange multipliers are interpreted as costate variables, and Lagrange multipliers are reformulated as the minimization of the Hamiltonian, in Pontryagin's minimum principle.
Exposition
For additional text and interactive applets